Очередная статья о нынешнем состоянии экономической науки. Ховард Дэвис (Howard Davies), в прошлом директор Лондонской школы экономики и первый глава британского регулятора в сфере финансовых рынков FSA со статьей "Economics in Denial" на Project Syndicate.
PARIS – In an exasperated outburst, just before he left the presidency of the European Central Bank, Jean-Claude Trichet complained that, “as a policymaker during the crisis, I found the available [economic and financial] models of limited help. In fact, I would go further: in the face of the crisis, we felt abandoned by conventional tools.”
Economics in Denial
by Howard DaviesPARIS – In an exasperated outburst, just before he left the presidency of the European Central Bank, Jean-Claude Trichet complained that, “as a policymaker during the crisis, I found the available [economic and financial] models of limited help. In fact, I would go further: in the face of the crisis, we felt abandoned by conventional tools.”
Trichet
went on to appeal for inspiration from other disciplines – physics,
engineering, psychology, and biology – to help explain the phenomena he
had experienced. It was a remarkable cry for help, and a serious
indictment of the economics profession, not to mention all those
extravagantly rewarded finance professors in business schools from
Harvard to Hyderabad.
So
far, relatively little help has been forthcoming from the engineers and
physicists in whom Trichet placed his faith, though there has been some
response. Robert May, an eminent climate change expert, has argued that
techniques from his discipline may help explain financial-market
developments. Epidemiologists have suggested that the study of how
infectious diseases are propagated may illuminate the unusual patterns
of financial contagion that we have seen in the last five years.
These
are fertile fields for future study, but what of the core disciplines
of economics and finance themselves? Can nothing be done to make them
more useful in explaining the world as it is, rather than as it is
assumed to be in their stylized models?
George
Soros has put generous funding behind the Institute for New Economic
Thinking (INET). The Bank of England has also tried to stimulate fresh
ideas. The proceedings of a conference that it organized earlier this
year have now been edited under the provocative title What’s the Use of Economics?
Some
of the recommendations that emerged from that conference are
straightforward and concrete. For example, there should be more teaching
of economic history. We all have good reason to be grateful that US
Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke is an expert on the Great
Depression and the authorities’ flawed policy responses then, rather
than in the finer points of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium
theory. As a result, he was ready to adopt unconventional measures when
the crisis erupted, and was persuasive in influencing his colleagues.
Many
conference participants agreed that the study of economics should be
set in a broader political context, with greater emphasis on the role of
institutions. Students should also be taught some humility. The models
to which they are still exposed have some explanatory value, but within
constrained parameters. And painful experience tells us that economic
agents may not behave as the models suppose they will.
But
it is not clear that a majority of the profession yet accepts even
these modest proposals. The so-called “Chicago School” has mounted a
robust defense of its rational expectations-based approach, rejecting
the notion that a rethink is required. The Nobel laureate economist
Robert Lucas has argued that the crisis was not predicted because
economic theory predicts that such events cannot be predicted. So all is
well.
And
there is disturbing evidence that news of the crisis has not yet
reached some economics departments. Stephen King, Group Chief Economist
of HSBC, notes that when he asks recent university graduates (and HSBC
recruits a large number of them) how much time they spent in lectures
and seminars on the financial crisis, “most admitted that the subject
had not even been raised.” Indeed, according to King, “Young economists
arrive in the financial world with little or no knowledge of how the
financial system operates.”
I
am sure they learn fast at HSBC. (In the future, one assumes, they will
learn quickly about money laundering regulations as well.) But it is
depressing to hear that many university departments are still in denial.
That is not because students lack interest: I teach a course at
Sciences Po in Paris on the consequences of the crisis for financial
markets, and the demand is overwhelming.
We
should not focus attention exclusively on economists, however. Arguably
the elements of the conventional intellectual toolkit found most
wanting are the capital asset pricing model and its close cousin, the
efficient-market hypothesis. Yet their protagonists see no problems to
address.
On
the contrary, the University of Chicago’s Eugene Fama has described the
notion that finance theory was at fault as “a fantasy,” and argues that
“financial markets and financial institutions were casualties rather
than causes of the recession.” And the efficient-market hypothesis that
he championed cannot be blamed, because “most investing is done by
active managers who don’t believe that markets are efficient.”
This
amounts to what we might call an “irrelevance” defense: Finance
theorists cannot be held responsible, since no one in the real world
pays attention to them!
Fortunately,
others in the profession do aspire to relevance, and they have been
chastened by the events of the last five years, when price movements
that the models predicted should occur once in a million years were
observed several times a week. They are working hard to understand why,
and to develop new approaches to measuring and monitoring risk, which is
the main current concern of many banks.
These
efforts are arguably as important as the specific and detailed
regulatory changes about which we hear much more. Our approach to
regulation in the past was based on the assumption that financial
markets could to a large extent be left to themselves, and that
financial institutions and their boards were best placed to control risk
and defend their firms.
These
assumptions took a hard hit in the crisis, causing an abrupt shift to
far more intrusive regulation. Finding a new and stable relationship
between the financial authorities and private firms will depend
crucially on a reworking of our intellectual models. So the Bank of
England is right to issue a call to arms. Economists would be right to
heed it.
Оригинал: Project Syndicate
Комментариев нет:
Отправить комментарий